“It’s
easier to imagine the end of the world than the end of capitalism,” everyone’s
favourite Marxist film critic, Slavoj Žižek, once remarked. Perhaps a
sudden fleeing of the imaginative capacity explains the strangely brain-dead
reaction of the science writer Ben Goldacre to the idea that the pharmaceutical
industry should, for the good of humanity, not be conducted on a capitalist
basis.
The question,
posed by the economist Harry Shutt, whose books have been admiringly reviewed
in this blog, was not complicated. Given that the pharmaceutical industry
appears totally unsuited to being run on a profit-maximising basis in
shareholder-owned companies, Shutt asked in The
Observer, wouldn’t its functions be better carried out by non-profit or
publicly-owed enterprises?
Goldacre is clearly a very intelligent person, whose Bad Science columns are oases of un-credulity
refuting the claims of corporate science. His book Bad Pharma says that drugs companies deliberately put dangerous or
useless drugs on the market. He’s no fool and no shill so why did this obvious
question precipitate such confusion?
Niall Ferguson has invaded my head
First, Goldacre said he was a realist, clearly implying that
he’d like a different way of running the industry but that wasn’t possible. But
by the next sentence, he revealed that he didn’t want a “central command state
economy” (Help! Niall Ferguson has invaded my head), a very jaded straw man and
definitely not what Shutt was advocating. This was followed, most bizarrely, by
the assertion that people in the drugs industry perpetuate acts of great evil,
not because they are innately evil, but because they work in a badly designed
system. This is precisely what Shutt
was saying – it’s a badly designed system, its acts are not the “fault” of the
individuals working in it, so change the system. As an answer, that lacks
something. It’s like saying 2+3 isn’t 5, it’s 5.
Finally, Goldacre says what he thinks should happen – a
“competent regulatory framework”. Are you still awake? Don’t worry, the boogie
man won’t get you because the good regulation fairy will stop him. Spoiler
alert. She won’t.
(Imagine, as an experiment, the reaction if state pharmaceutical agencies were
guilty of the foisting dangerous or dysfunctional drugs on the market. There
would be immediate and deafening calls for privatisation. You get an insight
into the balance of power, intellectual and otherwise, by the fact that critics
of the misdemeanours of corporate drug companies call merely for better
regulation.)
Let’s set aside for one moment the integral problem that
western “democratic” political systems, and frequently the politicians in them,
have been bought by corporations so that regulation is not remotely competent
or effective. (This is the Jeremy Grantham and Stewart Lansley
problem. Just because something should happen doesn’t mean it will).
Regulation/Smegulation
For the sake of argument, imagine an ideal world where the
state sits benevolently above the fray and government regulation can do its job
unimpeded. What would regulation actually do?
Bear in mind the recent claim by two eminent French
specialists that over half of the medicines prescribed in France are
either useless or dangerous.
20,000 people die annually as a result, they say. Goldacre’s book, Bad Pharma,
is specifically about the dangerous medicines that shouldn’t be out there, but
are. “… for several of the most important and enduring problems in medicine, we
have no idea what the best treatment is, because it’s not in anyone’s financial
interest to conduct any trials at all," he writes. And that doesn’t take into
the account the drugs, that while not harmful, do not serve any medical
purpose. “If you can get on to the market by making a me-too copycat drug that
represents little or no therapeutic advance and is even less effective than the
drugs that it copies, then you will,” says Goldacre.
So competent and effective regulation will, if it does
anything, radically reduce the number of pharmaceuticals that are allowed to go
on the market. Thereby massively hitting drug company profits (they are
currently the darlings of stock markets worldwide because they are so
profitable) and, in turn, the number of people they employ.
Thus, you are soon face to face with a fundamental conflict
of our capitalist system. An unavoidable collision between the impulse most
decent people share for reducing the anti-social effects of capitalism, against
the need for capitalism to prosper so that everyone can have good jobs and
incomes. We are, whether we like it or not, materially dependent on the system’s success. But a
successful system causes results, such as global warming and prescribing
dangerous medicines, that are inherently destructive.
Planned Regulatory Obsolescence
If regulation of the pharmaceutical industry were actually
competent, as Goldacre wants it to be, it would prevent capitalism from working
(actually it’s not working well anyway but effective
regulation would be another drag on profits). A 2009 UN report found that a
third of the profits of the world’s biggest 3,000 companies would be wiped out
if firms were forced to pay for the use, loss and damage to the environment
they cause. In other words,
truly effective environmental regulation would render capitalism impossible.
So regulation is, quite deliberately, not effective. It
allows, as research has found, just enough reform to buy off critics without
seriously impeding corporate priorities. In the end, Goldacre’s vision of a
“competent regulatory framework” is far more utopian than changing the system
so that profit maximization is not the modus operandi of pharmaceutical
companies.
And you don’t need to be Albert Einstein to work that out.