“The
best indicator of the left’s lack of trust in itself today is its fear of
crisis. A true left takes a crisis seriously, without illusions. Its basic
insight is that, although crises are painful and dangerous, they are
inevitable, and that they are the terrain on which battles have to be waged and
won.”
It’s a bad
habit to get into I know, quoting Slavoj Žižek, but the Žižek itch occasionally becomes irresistible.
Especially when it is proclaimed, as it was in the Guardian newspaper last Saturday, that the left is dazed and
confused by economic crisis.
“The right always knows what to do with economic turmoil –
it blames foreigners, and from there, the trajectory is pretty
straightforward,” wrote Zoe Williams.
“The left does not know what to do”
Come again? It was, to put it mildly, not always thus. In
previous eras, it was economic turmoil that gave the vital spark to the left.
The economic depression of the 1870s provided the backdrop to the growth of
unskilled trade unionism and the proliferation of social democratic, Marxist
parties.
The turmoil, economic and otherwise, of the First World War
led directly to the Russian Revolution and near revolution across Europe. The
Great Depression of the 1930s saw the greatest union recruitment drive in US history.
So why now the blank minds in response to contemporary
economic turmoil?
Sinister uneconomicus
It is because for more than thirty years the left has not
been interested in economics. It has accepted that that battle has been lost
and ceded that ground to the right. The focus has been on social inclusion. As
Richard Wolff has elucidated here (last talk), the
strategy has been to bring the marginalised – ethnic minorities, women, the
poor, disabled people - into the system and treat them decently. To be sure the
left was in favour of the catch-all “regulation” but the inner workings of the
capitalist machine were taken to be unchallengeable, and thus ignored.
Now the machine is spluttering and no-one seems to know what
to do about it.
This left strategy, though it has some undoubted successes,
has now been revealed to be a historic error. It was unquestionably naïve to
expect any kind of progressive outcome from a ‘private’ economy that generates
immense inequality and instability and is founded on hierarchical, innately
competitive, profoundly undemocratic institutions.
In the words of the US economist, Stan Bowles, “how we
regulate our exchanges and coordinate our disparate economic activities
influence what kind of people we become … The economy – its markets, workplaces
and other sites – is a gigantic school. Its rewards encourage the development
of particular skills and attitudes while other potentials lay fallow or
atrophy.”
Even you may score some wins here and there, you will lose
overall.
“Give my creation life!”
This economic abandonment has happened across the board, it’s
not confined to the liberal left. The recent call for a new Left party from
film director Ken Loach and others included a plea to “regenerate the economy”
– a phrase that conjures an image of Oxbridge experts twiddling some knobs and
pushing some buttons, approving a motorway or rail link here and there, and,
hey presto! The economy is “regenerated”.
Merely because Keynesianism is not being practiced by the
austerians in Whitehall and Frankfurt
does not mean that Keynesianism works anymore or does not have fatal flaws. Austerity is awful. Keynesianism
is not austerity. Therefore, Keynesianism is the answer is not a syllogism that
should persuade anyone. Unfortunately, it seems to.
What a new left has to do is not just defend the welfare state and not just oppose austerity but start viewing intractable economic crisis
as a road, a long and winding one admittedly, to a democratic economy.
Let the people, not the banks, decide
The seeds of this new approach can be glimpsed in plans for
a people’s assembly against austerity and public consultations on how to reform the economy. The
writer Dan Hind has argued that the destination of multi-billion stimulus
measures should be determined, not by government ministers and civil servants,
but by citizen assemblies in every Parliamentary constituency.
Not only could people discuss which council cuts they wished
to reverse, but, in Hind’s words, “New houses could be built in collaboration
with the people who would live in them. Transport projects could be devised
that serve the interests of citizens rather those of wealthy
investors and their many friends in government. We could have public
buildings of unparalleled magnificence at a fraction of the cost that the
unreformed private sector would expect to charge. New libraries and labs could
make our universities and colleges a wonder of the world.”
In addition, a plethora of new co-operative, not capitalist,
businesses could be funded.
What this kind of approach would do is make a first breach
in the automatic assumption that decisions about investment are the
unquestionable prerogative of private banks and the stock market. In David
Schweickart’s vision of a post-capitalist future, new investment, funded by a tax on enterprises, is decided by
citizen assemblies and funneled through public banks in each region. As new
investment is a concern of all of society it is should be decided, as much as
is possible, by all of society, not by the profit maximizing interests of
Barclays or HSBC.
In Britain,
there have already been the first stirrings of recognition on this issue,
through the 2011 campaign that, as a bailed-out, state-owned, bank, RBS should
not invest in tar sands mining. That original insight needs to be built on and
expanded.
For a new left, the simple mantra, “austerity bad/public
spending good” is nowhere near sufficient.