“Manual
work is the ideal which is held before the young and is the basis of all
ethical teaching,” so said Bertrand Russell in his essay, In Praise of Idleness.
Russell was
writing about Stalin’s Russia
of the 1930s but delete ‘manual’ and you have an uncannily accurate description
of the mores of contemporary Britain,
a country that, in the opinion of the author Mark Fisher, has embraced “market
Stalinism.” 20% of young people are unemployed but work, paid or unpaid, is
exalted as both an ethical and practical ideal. “Arbeit Macht Frei” in the words of one Daily Mail columnist. Yes really.
“What will
happen” Russell went on to ask, “when the point has been reached where
everybody could be comfortable without working long hours?” We now know what will
happen – an intensification of the idealisation of work, a joyless embrace of
the tyranny of immediate self-interest.
A kind of tunnel vision that refuses to allow questions about the ultimate
purpose of work to intrude.
It is
tempting to wonder about the curious capacity of ideology to become more
intransigent and boastful at precisely the moment when the objective justification
for it dissipates. But there is also a stubborn nugget of truth at work here,
albeit one fanned mercilessly by the Right. A human being, says Russell in his
essay, inevitably consumes a certain amount of the products of human labour in
his or her lifetime. Work is, to a greater or lesser extent, disagreeable. It
is, therefore, unjust that a person should consume more than s/he produces.
“To this
extent, and to this extent only” says Russell, “there is a ‘duty’ to work”. Or,
in the unforgiving words of St Paul,
“if any would not work, neither should he eat”.
The latter
threat is at the heart of the Conservative assault on social security benefit
claimants in Britain;
an offensive, emboldened by opinion polls, that has resulted in many people in
the seventh richest economy in the world having no food. Not insufficient food.
No food. The strivers versus shirkers rhetoric (however divorced from reality)
is founded on stoking a resentment that, while you have to go through the
disagreeable experience of working every day, others do nothing. That it
thrives by inflaming resentment, rather than resting on economic logic, is demonstrated
by the fact that the work obligation destroys paid employment.
Heaven knows I’m
miserable now
One way to
assuage this sense of resentment could be, of course, to make work more
agreeable. But that doesn’t chime at all with the priorities of the age of
austerity where everything should get worse. It’s ironic that, whereas in the
1980s the Thatcherite Right taunted the Left by saying it wanted to ‘level down’,
now the reverse is true. The UK
welfare benefit freeze – all benefits will, including tax credits, will rise by
an under-inflation 1% - is justified by
the fact that employees are experiencing real term pay cuts. Cuts to public
sector pensions are presented as reasonable because these state pensions are
more generous than their private sector equivalents, where final salary schemes
are becoming extinct. It is proposed to shorten school holidays in order to
compete with China.
Level down. Make life more miserable.
But there
is still a dilemma here for a genuinely radical Left that isn’t in thrall to
the work obsession, and is prepared to confront the question, “what is the
point of work?” Without many of the basic commodities of modern society, life
would be more a slog than it already is. Consumption, in a sense, makes life
meaningful. “The problem with full supermarket shelves is that they’re
not enough — not that they’re unwelcome or trivial,” writes Seth
Ackerman in an illuminating essay, The Red and the Black.
“The citizens of Communist societies,” he goes on,
“experienced the paucity, shoddiness and uniformity of their goods not merely
as inconveniences; they experienced them as violations of their basic rights.”
Many simple conveniences – lights that work, TVs that function, bath plugs that
fit – instantly loom very large in importance when they malfunction. The second
biggest cause of fires in Moscow
in the 1980s, says the economist Ha-Joon Chang, was exploding TV sets. Despite the
implications of 3D printing,
and the inescapable fact that material production requires fewer and fewer people, useful commodities do not as yet make or repair themselves. Not
everything can be performed by robots.
Can I do the mindless, repetitive unpleasant, dirty, smelly jobs
please?
It is not mindlessly repeating conservative tautologies to
point out that someone has to bake the bread, make the laptops, distribute the
food, repair the washing machines, care for the elderly and clean the offices.
To do, in other words, the disagreeable activities that few people would freely
volunteer to do. At the same time you have to be living in a galaxy far, far
away not to appreciate that many contemporary jobs are “socially useless” –
hedge fund manager, sales director, lawyer, public relations executive, many
types of manager etc etc. These
jobs solely exist to further the interests of the organisations that create
them. The question for a post-capitalist Left is how do you get useful,
necessary and disagreeable activities done, while excluding activities that are
either superfluous or harmful?
One answer to the first half of that equation is a market of
worker, not capitalist, controlled firms. The ability of firms to freely enter
a market is, says Ackerman in the above essay, the way to avoid the scarcity of
useful goods that characterised the Soviet bloc. But markets, worker-controlled
or otherwise, also have it in their DNA to exploit opportunities to sell, go
way beyond actual needs and try to out-muscle the competition. They are
socially useless as well as socially useful.
Bertrand Russell’s answer to this dilemma was what he termed
a “sensible” organisation of production. “Owing to the absence of any central control (my italics) over
production,” he wrote in In Praise of
Idleness, “we produce hosts of things that are not wanted.” The presence of
“central control”, he implied, would prevent any employee from being compelled
to work more than four hours a day. There would be no unemployment and enough
for everybody. Russell was more of an anarchist than a Communist but his
embrace of “central control” still implies the kind of state central planning, whose
pathologies we are far more attuned to now than when Russell was writing in
1932. One post-capitalist writer, David Schweickart, has specifically ruled out
any “central authority”. The
residual question that Russell’s “sensible organisation” solution doesn’t
address is who decides what is and is not wanted and how?
It is possible for the government to legislate
that no-one can work more than four hours a day, in much the same way that the
French government instituted a 35 hour week in 2000. But over and above the
difficulty that the direction of travel is resolutely in the opposite direction
(we must all work harder we are told by politicians), the intrinsic problem
with this solution is that the government imposes sensible limits on an
unreconstructed capitalist productive system that is full to the brim with
socially useless activities, and will work tirelessly to nullify the
work-limiting legislation. The “workers’ control” solution to overwork would
entail the employees of particular firms insisting on a more civilised
work-life balance, and/or rotation of work tasks, because they are in charge of
the enterprise and they want it that way. But, externally, markets don’t
produce “sensible organisation”. The firms within a market have to react to
competition and the need to make a profit. A third solution can be seen in the popular assemblies that have sprung up in Europe in
response to economic collapse and dysfunctional “democratic” political
institutions. They have begun
to set up cooperatives to provide for needs that are not satisfied by a failing
economic system. A decade or so ago, the assemblies in Argentina in response to an analogous
situation, created enterprises such as community bakeries. The relevance to
this argument is that the assembly controls the enterprise and can insist upon
humane working hours. But the scope of these assembly-controlled enterprises
is, as yet, limited and way short of what any meaningful economy would comprise.
I can’t highlight the solution.
But the disconnect between, on the one side, the declining demand for paid
labour and the vanishing objective need for work, and on the other, the social
purpose of production and the desire for a meaningful and spacious life, will
bring immense pressure to bear to find a solution.
But to crystallise the case for radically reduced working
hours I believe we should concentrate on its opposite. What, in other words, is
the point of not working, and that isn’t a non sequitur. It is this question of
non-work that I want to examine in the final part of this post.
You can read Part One here by the way
And here is the final part
You can read Part One here by the way
And here is the final part