I think it encapsulates an integral part of the impasse we are now facing. Good that other people are now catching up, albeit two years late ....
"There are many kinds of capitalism. Free market capitalism, which easily morphs into the dominance of corporations. Or social market capitalism, in which there is a larger role for the state and workers are represented on company boards. There is even state capitalism, in which everybody works for state enterprises, which pass themselves off as socialist, but exploit people just the same.
But
now perhaps there are only two kinds of capitalism which count.
Successful capitalism and capitalism which is too successful for its own
good. The consequences of each are different but equally horrible in
their own way.
Back
in the roaring nineties successful capitalism was thought to be the
only game in town. In Britain, Tony Blair’s New Labour exemplified the
social democratic acceptance of capitalism. The “market” would hum along
unmolested in the background and the government would skim off the tax
revenue. Labour spokespeople waxed lyrical about the wealth-creating
genius of the private sector and spent the proceeds on tax credits for
the working poor, the National Health Service – health spending went up
by 30 per cent – and relieving child poverty. It was, in essence, a
deal.
But,
said Left and green critics of capitalism, this was a myopic
accommodation, trading short-term advantages for long-term disaster.
Growth – the social ecologist Murray Bookchin said expecting capitalism
not to grow was like expecting a lion to become vegetarian – might
support enlarged public spending but would eventually make the planet
unliveable.
In 2007, a British professor of engineering worked out that, based on an economy growing at three per cent a year, we would consume resources equivalent to all those we have consumed since humanity began as a species by 2040. In 33 years. I think the word you are grasping for is unsustainable.
As the writer Mark Fisher
has said, successful capitalism was based on a fantasy: “A
presupposition that resources are infinite, that the earth itself is
merely a husk which capital can at a certain point slough off like a
used skin, and that any problem can be solved by the market”.
To
believe in successful capitalism you had to stick your index fingers in
your ears and sing “la, la, la” very loudly. But both celebrators and
critics agreed that capitalism worked.
Oh shit
But just as capitalism was swaggering around the globe, assured in its invincibility, disaster struck.
The
global economic meltdown happened, the worst economic contraction since
the Great Depression. $14.5 trillion of value was wiped from global
companies.
The former masters of the universe, who meet at Davos, now speak of a “dystopian future” destroying
the gains of globalization.“For the first time in generations, many
people no longer believe that their children will grow up to enjoy a
higher standard of living than theirs,” they warn.
Something had gone badly wrong.
The
conventional explanation was that investment banks were too reckless,
financial speculation overreached itself and the economy became
dangerously skewed. But, in truth, capitalism had become too successful
for its own good.
In
the US, where the crisis was hatched, wages had stagnated since the
mid-70s, while productivity – worker ouput that the employer benefits
from – raced ahead. The result was not only spiralling inequality (the
US was actually more equal than many western European countries in early
‘70s) and burgeoning corporate profits, but an orgy of personal
borrowing so that consumption could be maintained despite the fact that
earnings weren’t going up.
A
cursory look at recent US economic history shows a series of bubbles. A
massive stock market crash struck in 2000. The price of shares is
dependent on the expectation of future corporate profits so crashes
occur when there is a realisation of total over-optimism about profits.
The crash was stopped from turning into a recession by reducing interest
rates to below
the rate of inflation for three years. Borrowing doubled – the house
price and house building bubble ensued – but when that burst so
spectacularly in 2007 there were no more bubbles left. Reality – the
reality of stagnating earnings – could be evaded no longer.
A
dusty old critique of capitalism suddenly became remarkably persuasive.
That held that capitalism was inherently self-destructive. Each
employer tries to keep wages, which are just another cost, as low as
possible. But if they are too successful in that endeavour, the same
workers with the low wages won’t be able to play their other vital role
in capitalism, that of consumers of goods. Economic health depends upon
the employer impulse to keep wages down being frustrated by another
countervailing power. Capitalism can be too successful for its own good.
Flatliners
Worryingly
for economic health, the US capacity for stagnating earnings has proved
a very effective export. In the UK, earnings grew strongly throughout
the ’80s and ‘90s but have flat-lined since 2003, four years before the onset of the ‘great recession’. Worker productivity, meanwhile, has kept on steaming ahead. Post-downturn
wages rises in Britain are currently half the rate of inflation.
Average wages are forecast to be no higher in 2015 than they were in
2001. France and Germany have followed a similar trajectory. Researchers describe an acute “decoupling”of earnings from growth.
The UK Resolution Foundation, which has produced a series of reports on living standards, worries that a return to growth won’t necessarily mean rising wages. Stagnating earnings also ensure burgeoning inequality (yes, it can get worse).
But
there is another larger, elephant in the room, problem. The US
experience demonstrates that you can’t, to use the economists’ elegant
term, “decouple” growth from earnings forever, without eventually
destroying growth as well (in industrialised, western countries at
least, the experience of developing, exporting countries like India
seems to be different). Earnings are purchasing power, in
economics-speak ‘demand’, and growth cannot survive indefinitely without
purchasing power.
The
economic vista in front of us is that of a tsunami of bank debt
inexorably making its way to shore. At the same time, earnings power
which could lift countries out of recession, is exhausted. The level of
personal borrowing is huge and, as we have seen, earnings stagnated or declined even before the recession.
That
last factor cannot be wished away, or undone by governments even if
they were inclined to. The reasons for stagnating earnings are analysed
by a Resolution Foundation report.
Technological change has obviated the need for low-skilled workers,
firms have given precedence to share dividends over the pay of ordinary
workers, outsourcing has increased, and the bargaining position of
workers has been diluted. None of these factors will be reversed given
current trends and the balance of power politically and economically.
The globe stops warming
It doesn’t have to be this way, you cry. And you’d be right. The Resolution Foundation report, Painful Separation,
finds that in some European countries, namely Finland, Sweden and
Denmark, there has been only mild divergence between economic growth and
median pay. It is no accident that in Scandinavian countries, they say,
“Recession? What recession?”
They
haven’t killed the goose that lays the golden egg. They, if it isn’t
stretching the metaphor too far, nurture their goose. They have
effective countervailing powers like strong trade unions. They haven’t
left successful capitalism behind. But there is a catch.
Amid
all the deleterious social effects of the great recession – the
homelessness, the riots, the suicides, the divorces – there was one
undoubtedly progressive, though unintended, result. The sudden drop in
economic activity achieved something international protocols and
protesters invading airport runways had failed to. The rate of global
warming was arrested. For only the fourth time in 50 years, carbon emissions fell.
It
is clear that the kind of capitalism that Anglo-Saxon societies have
been living through for the past 30 years is an ineffective form of
capitalism. Growth rates have been unimpressive, financial crises have
become more frequent and earnings have been held down. Too much power
has been given to or taken by corporations and the rich. Capitalism has
become too successful for its own good.
The South Korean economist, Ha-Joon Chang, in his book 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism,
argues convincingly that what we call “free market economics” has been
shown to fail spectacularly. He puts the case for more assertive
government control, different forms of ownership, the outlawing of
financial products like derivatives, and the rebalancing of the economy
away from finance and into the long-term production of manufactured
goods. Capitalism can work if the harnesses are placed back on and it is
guided in the public interest.
In
other words, a return to successful capitalism, a capitalism that is in
rude health. Chang eulogises the “miraculous” performance of South
Korea in the ‘80s and ‘90s, which grew at an average of six per cent
year. China today, he says, illustrates what can be done if free market
prescriptions aren’t followed.
The
problem isn’t the economic reasoning. The problem is that the world,
ecologically, cannot cope with the replication of the Chinese or South
Korean economic success stories. If earnings in the US had continued to
track GDP growth, as they had done from 1945 to 1973, the average
household would have earned $80,000 a year, not $50,000 as they in fact
do. Even accounting for the spike in borrowing, consumption has been
suppressed in US as capitalism has become too successful for its own
good. It is revealing that Chang mentions the word “environment” just
once in his entire book.
Chang, like John Maynard Keynes seventy years ago, wants to save capitalism from itself.
Post-capitalism
But
the truth is that neither successful capitalism, nor capitalism that is
too successful for its own good, presents a remotely desirable
prospect.
The latter leads, in Ann Pettifor’s words, to “dramatically
higher levels of unemployment, the loss of savings, home foreclosures,
bankruptcies, emigration, suicides, divorce, social unrest and political
upheaval – to name but a few of the consequences.” The former provides
a swifter route to the dystopian future of global warming.
Awareness
of the awful consequences of both alternatives leads to the realisation
that the only rational option left is some form of post-capitalism. It
doesn’t mean, in the caricature of one British government minister,
everyone running around in Maoist boiler suits,
but it does entail an end to the growth fetish and ensuring a secure
standard of living for everyone. What “post-capitalism” is like in
detail is what we should be concentrating on now.