It has
become fashionable again to speak of the contradictions of capitalism. Radical
geographer David Harvey is writing a book about the 17 Contradictions of Capitalism (don’t ask why but critical economic
thinkers like Harvey and Ha-Joon Chang with his 23 Things They don’t tell you about Capitalism seem to have
this fascination with random numbers). For example, one of Harvey’s contradictions concerns market
demand. One way to ensure demand is healthy in an economy is through high wages
but if they rise too much they eat into profit. So, since the 1970s economies
have definitively swung the other way, suppressing labour and trade unions and
trying to restore profit. But that just creates the opposite problem, with
employees whose wages are being squeezed unable to afford the products produced
by firms and turning to borrowing as a consequence - creating the economic
problems we are painfully aware of. That’s a contradiction – whichever way you
turn under capitalism (a system in
which employees and employers have conflicting interests), insoluble problems rear
up.
But I want
to talk about another contradiction of contemporary capitalism, albeit one which has
attracted less attention, but is still a contradiction in the sense of
attributes being in conflict with one another. That is modern-day capitalism’s
instability, indeed worsening instability, countered by the determination of business
representatives, politicians and the state to always stop it from collapsing
completely. That is why, I would suggest, we inhabit this strange and
conservative world.
Bubble Trouble
Capitalist
instability is attributed by Keynesian and Marxian economists to the business
cycle: competing firms produce more and more goods which eventually outgrow the
ability of workers to consume them, glutting the market and causing
bankruptcies and recession. Once this process of destruction has been played
out, the process can start all over again. It is one of the features of the
last thirty years that this instability has become chronic. Britain, for
example, has suffered three major recessions and spikes in unemployment since
1980, in contrast to none between the end of World War Two and the mid-1970s.What
has happened is that the instability of the business cycle has been
supplemented by the greater volatility of a financialised economy. According to
the Cambridge University economist Ha-Joon Chang,
virtually no country in the world had a banking crisis between the end of the
Second World War and the mid-70s. Between the mid-70s and late ‘80s, 5-10% of
countries did. This grew to 20% in the 1990s and then to 35% with the onset of
the 2008 global financial crisis.
Another way
to look at this process is as a series of financial bubbles which went the way
of all bubbles. “The thing you need to realize,” wrote Paul Krugman in August,
“is that the whole era since 1985 has been one of successive bubbles. There was
a huge commercial real estate bubble in the 80s, closely tied up with the
S&L crisis; a bubble in capital flows to Asia
in the mid 90s; the dotcom bubble; the housing bubble; and now, it seems, the
BRIC bubble. There was nothing comparable in the 50s and 60s.”
The
bursting of these bubbles caused major real world effects. The East Asian
crisis of the 1990s, referred to by Krugman, precipitated mass unemployment in
the region and more foreign ownership of companies in countries like South Korea.
What he modestly calls the “housing bubble” became the 2007-8 global financial
crisis whose effects are still being intensely felt now. But the point to keep
in mind is that action by governments prevented these crises from following
their natural free market course and becoming far more destructive than they
actually were.
Don’t purge the
rottenness out of the system
Marxian
economist Andrew Kliman has pointed out that the 1930s Great Depression was the
last time there was a genuinely free market response to one of capitalism’s
periodic busts. Then US Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon wanted to “purge the
rottenness out of the system” by liquidating stocks, labour, real estate and
farmers. “The amount of capital value that was destroyed during the Depression
was far greater than advocates of laissez-faire policies had expected,” writes
Kliman in The Failure of Capitalist Production: Underlying Causes of the Great Recession, “and the persistence
of severely depressed conditions led to a significant radicalization of working
people. Policymakers have not wanted this to happen again, so now they
intervene with monetary and fiscal policies in order to prevent the full-scale
destruction of capital value. This explains why subsequent downturns have not
been nearly as severe as the Depression.”
If you want
to see an example of “significant radicalization” that policy-makers are so
desperate to avoid, look to Greece now, where both the socialist Syriza and Fascist Golden Dawn are on the rise, and in danger of eclipsing the
conventional, capitalist parties. The suffering in Greece is politically created, as
opposed to just being an outcome of economic slump, but it shows what the
“full-scale destruction of capital value” could look like and bring in its
train and why policy-makers are so terrified of universalising it.
The
economist, Harry Shutt, has said the period since the 1970s has been
characterised by a “progressive postponing of the evil day” on the part of
ruling elites. The 1987 stock market crash was nipped in the bud by pumping
money into the banks, the Latin American debt crisis resulted in public
bail-outs, the response to Russian hedge fund crisis of the late ‘90s was a
recapitalisation of financial institutions by the US government to the tune of
$3.6 billion and when the dot.com share bubble burst in 2000, interest rates in
the US were held below the rate of inflation for three years in order to
encourage borrowing and avert a recession.
All these
government interventions to stop capitalist busts following their natural
course are dwarfed by what happened in 2007/8. A conservative estimate puts the
cost to the public at arresting the crash at $7.7 trillion in the US and £1.5 trillion in Britain. There
is a consensus that this intervention had to happen, governments had to stop
this “sucker going down”, in the poetic words of George W Bush. Without action,
companies would have been unable to pay their staff, ATMs would have not
dispensed cash, trains and buses would not have run. The system would have
collapsed, with untold and unpredictable human consequences and suffering.
There was
political unanimity about the necessity of government intervention. For the
Right and Centre and faux-Left, intervention meant “capital value” was saved.
For the Left, intervention meant that the structures on which ordinary people
depend for the livelihoods were stopped from going under. Allowing everything
to be liquidated, as Andrew Mellon recommended in 1929, was not regarded as an
option. Referring to Mellon, the famous left-wing economist, John Kenneth
Galbraith wrote in 1954: “a developing depression would not now be met with a
fixed determination to make it worse”. The contemporary mainstream Left, Right
and Centre would all concur.
Groundhog Day
But, as a
result of this consensus, little attention is paid to the consequences of the
fact that complete collapse was not allowed to happen, that “full-scale destruction of
capital value” was prevented: the huge insolvent institutions bailed out (which,
if the market had had its way, would now be in the dustbin of history), simply
said ‘thanks very much’ and went on acting in precisely the same way as they did prior to the crash occurring.
That is why there is a Groundhog Day quality
to the UK economic ‘recovery’ based, as it is, on rising house prices and
household debt; factors which caused the crash in the first place. The only
purging allowed is inflicted on those at the bottom of society – the
unemployed, benefit claimants, the disabled. Those at the summit are the
recipients of government intervention, not laissez-faire. Nothing was solved
and nothing has changed, not least declining real wages which necessitate
greater household debt for consumption to go on happening.
The
processes that aim to re-balance the economy, which almost all politicians say
they want, cannot happen because the dominant financial institutions, which in
the years leading up to the crash made the economy so unbalanced, are still dominant
- because they were artificially stopped from going bust. Instead of innovation and organic growth, you get stagnation, monopoly and the unalterered ascendancy of finance. Contemporary politics
is characterised by a fervent desire for the benefits of capitalism, but an
equally strong aversion to experiencing its negatives.
Looked at
another way, it is possible to have
the advantages of capitalism - healthy economic growth, innovation, new firms
replacing old - but only if you accept periodic destructiveness and all that that entails. But, of course,
the last time this destructiveness was allowed unbridled reign, in the Great
Depression of the 1930s, the results were not only the immediate ones of mass
unemployment, hunger and destitution but the later, though no less attributable
ones, of Nazism, Stalinism and the physical annihilation of World War Two. Only
after this orgy of destruction had played itself out could the so-called
“Golden Age” of capitalism begin.
Thus there
is a determination on the part of ruling elites to perpetually put a lid on the
instability of capitalism for fear of what will ensue if they don't. But this inherent instability keeps bubbling up nonetheless.
The question now is: are ruling elites merely (quite literally) buying time, in
a futile attempt to avert a systemic meltdown that will inevitably happen eventually?
Will the next one blow the lid off?
Note: I’m
indebted to this article, Forever blowing bubbles, on the UK Independent Working Class Association site, which
sparked the idea for this post.
No comments:
Post a Comment