Showing posts with label world trade. Show all posts
Showing posts with label world trade. Show all posts

Saturday, 15 February 2020

Global carbon emissions stop rising (again)


According to the Financial Times, the head of the International Energy Agency (IEA), Fatih Birol, is “hopeful” that global CO2 emissions have finally peaked after news that they were flat in 2019.

Emissions have been downgraded after preliminary predictions in December last year that they rose by 0.6% in 2019. Now, however, it’s been revealed that emissions from energy use were unchanged from 2018, at 33 gigatonnes.

Birol was optimistic what the “clean energy transition” was rapidly accelerating and that emissions will now start to decline. “2019 is a year that gives me hope that the 2020s will be a decade of relief,” he said.

The trouble is that we’ve been here before.  For three years in the middle of the last decade – 2014-2016 – emissions were flat. Many, including the IEA, celebrated the fact that carbon emissions were finally decoupling from economic growth, as global GDP showed a steady, if unspectacular, rise.

According to the IEA, 2014-16 saw “strong energy improvements” and “low-carbon technology deployment”.  Strangely, however, this was a false dawn as the “dynamics changed” and demand for clean technology was not sustained. Emissions resumed their upward path in 2017 and 2018.

As previously noted in this blog, this mystery – why there were “strong energy improvements” in 2014-16 and again in 2019, but not in 2017-18 – becomes a lot less impenetrable if world trade is taken into account. According to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Status of World Trade 2017 report, world trade grew at less than 2 per cent a year from 2011-14, declined by 10 per cent in 2015 – during which time the profitability of global shipping companies sank like a stone – and dropped by a further 3 per cent in 2016. But trade rebounded strongly in 2017 and 2018.

Likewise in 2019 world trade hit the buffers. “World commerce is deteriorating rapidly”, noted the New York Times in October last year, reporting on the slashing of the World Trade Organization’s forecast of world merchandise trade levels – from a 2.6% increase in April to 1.2% in the autumn. Just last week, it was revealed that US imports and exports both fell in 2019. In the context of the trade war with China, US exports to, and imports from, that country, both dropped.

This is the background to the flatlining of carbon emissions in 2019.

To put things another way, the only occasions when global carbon emissions have not risen this century have been when world trade has also been depressed. The same is not true of economic growth per se which has seen significant, although below average, rises when emissions have been static.

What we have never seen is the combination of robust world trade and stagnant, or falling, CO2 emissions. Given the unerring commitment of the world’s liberal-capitalist establishment to both ‘open trade’ and the ‘clean energy transition’, this is what needs to happen if the IPCC’s scenario of droughts, inundation of coastal areas, crop failures and massive refugees flow is not to come to pass. In fact, what is necessary is a huge and sustained drop in CO2 emissions – of about 15% a year from now until 2040 (15th para).

My guess is that this is because the two things are mutually contradictory.


Friday, 3 January 2020

Hyper-globalised Capitalism is Slowly Killing Civilisation


It is easier, according to the adage, to imagine the end of the world than the end of capitalism. Judging by the muted reaction to the raging Australian bush fires, the truth of that observation is being borne out. But actually it may be worse than that – it is easier to imagine the end of the world than the end of the particular version of hyper-globalized capitalism we live under.

Over the previous decade – in spite of calamitous warnings of what lies in store if massive cuts are not instituted – carbon emissions have continue to rise. Except that is for three years (2014-2016) when coincidentally world trade – but not, strangely, global economic growth – shrank.

Look closely and 2019 follows a similar pattern. According to first estimates, carbon emissions continued to increase last year, but the rate of increase – at 0.6% – was smaller than before. It compares to 1.4% in 2017 and 1.7% in 2018, according to one means of calculation, and 1.5% and 2.1% according to another. It should also be noted that the 0.6% estimate is based solely on the first 9-10 months of last years and could be revised downwards.

Coincidentally, 2019 was also a decidedly rough year for world trade – when it faced the headwinds of a trade war between Trump’s America and China. The imposition of unilateral tariffs on goods by both countries undoubtedly had a dampening effect on trade levels. After the strong rebound of 2017 and 2018, trade suffered. In October, the World Trade Organisation revised its April estimate of a 2.6% increase in world merchandise trade downwards to just 1.2%.  But given that a – possibly temporary – truce has been called in the trade war, rates may return to more ‘normal’ levels in 2020 – unless of course a global recession, or war, intervenes.

The conventional perception of world trade is that it involves the one-time transport of finished goods – clothes, cars or refrigerators for example – to the consumer. Undoubtedly that’s part of it but not all, or even most, of the story. Most world trade now occurs within firms during the production process. It is part of what are called ‘global value chains’ – where multi-national corporations scour the world for the most cost-effective and appropriate venue for making one part of a commodity – the engineering of components in one country, assembly in another (poorer) one and branding in yet another. The sinews of intra-firm trade between numerous countries involved in the construction of an iPhone illustrate the ‘new nomadism.’

But Apple is far from unique. Global value chains make up, it is estimated, 2/3rds of world trade. The ‘value chain’ of US vehicle manufacturer, General Motors, comprises 20,000 businesses worldwide, while the imported parts can make up 50% of cars ostensibly ‘made in the USA’. The World Bank defines global value chains in the following way:

Companies used to make things primarily in one country. That has all changed. Today, a single finished product often results from manufacturing and assembly in multiple countries, with each step in the process adding value to the end product.

There is a glaring contradiction between, on the one hand, wanting to reduce the world’s carbon emissions and, on the other, aiming to increase, or shore up, the volume of global free trade. Yet any number of conservative, centrist, liberal and social-democratic politicians happily exist in such a state of cognitive dissonance.

Just as it makes no sense for a consumer to proclaim a commitment to the environment while simultaneously seeking out the cheapest products regardless of how they were made, it makes no sense for corporations – and their backers in the media and politics – to say arresting global warming is their overwhelmingly priority whilst, at the same time, pursuing a production strategy whose fundamental amoral, profit-maximising purpose ensures that it won’t happen. Yet the latter is precisely what our political and economic system has reified as sacrosanct and non-negotiable.

And we are talking about maximising profit here, not the difference between profit and no profit at all. Apple, for example, would still have an ample profit margin if its iPhones were assembled in the US, not China. Just not quite as big.

But it is not, sadly, a question of corporations simply pursuing their institutionally selfish aims without the public in their domestic countries knowing or approving. They also enable us to physically and mentally outsource the problem of global warming to other countries. They are the ones burning coal to produce commodities flooding the global market, while we are ‘doing our bit’ by reducing our territorial emissions (ironically largely because we have off-shored dirty production to those very countries). It becomes a matter of out of sight, out of mind. And that suits a lot of people just fine.

Saturday, 29 December 2018

The Carbon Lie, part two


The crucial role of international trade in global warming

I’m going to do some speculating. The reason the rate of embodied, trade-based carbon emissions discussed in part one is so significant is that overall CO2 emissions are intimately connected – not to the degree of economic growth per se – but to the amount of international trade.

Foreign direct investment – and thus global trade – mushroomed from the 1990s onwards as globalisation took root. Manufacturing companies upped and left the deindustrializing West and relocated to countries like China*.The products they made had to be transported back to consumers in rich countries via container ships and aeroplanes and therefore emissions shot up. Between 2000 and 2008 the emissions’ growth rate reached 3.4%.

Everything came to a juddering halt in 2008 with the global financial crisis. But the respite was short-lived – in 2010 emissions’ growth returned with a vengeance, hitting 5.9%.

Then something strange happened. Global economic growth continued, albeit at a historically subdued level, but carbon emissions did not follow suit. They were, in fact, flat for three straight years (2014-2016). For the first time ever emissions were not rising in tandem with GDP growth. This prompted notions that the world had reached peak emissions and that CO2 pollution was finally “decoupling from economic activity”.

However, such hopes were dashed almost as soon as they were raised. In 2017, carbon emissions started growing again, reaching a historic high.

These developments become a lot less puzzling when global trade, as opposed bare economic growth levels, is brought into the picture. According to the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) Status of World Trade 2017 report, world trade grew at less than 2 per cent a year from 2011-14, declined by 10 per cent in 2015 – during which time the profitability of global shipping companies sank like a stone – and dropped by a further 3 per cent in 2016. However, reports UNCTAD, the “dismal performance” of world trade over the previous eight years came to an end during 2017.  

After an unpromising beginning at the start of the year, “Trade growth”, notes the report, “picked up substantially in the second and third quarters of 2017”. In the fourth quarter, trade was expected to achieve growth rates 10% higher than those of 2016. Trade was anticipated to outperform GDP growth in 2017 (4 percent points compared with 3.6), something it had done consistently since the middle of the 19th century, except for the period 2011-2016, when coincidentally carbon emissions remained flat or fell. Importantly, noted UNCTAD, trade growth was widespread across both developed and emerging economies.

Hence, the years in which global CO2 emissions did not rise were concurrent with declining world trade, and the return to rising emissions synchronous with the revival of world trade. I don’t think that’s a coincidence.

It is true that global economic growth has increased as well, but to nothing like the same degree. According to the International Monetary Fund it was 3.1% in 2015, 3.2% in 2016, 3.6% in 2017 and projected to reach 3.7% in 2018: an incremental rise but nothing spectacular. If trade growth – as anticipated – has continued into 2018, it is a sure fire bet that carbon emissions will have increased as well.

Why does international trade cause emissions? Through a combination of the pollution caused in the manufacture of goods or extraction of raw materials and in transporting them often thousands of miles to end user markets.

The Establishment in denial

But this connection between global trade and global warming is anathema to both liberal and conservative commentators. Donald Trump, for example, is roundly lambasted for stoking a trade war with China by introducing tariffs on commodities like steel. Such restraints on trade and protectionism are seen as dangerous and potentially leading, as they have done in the past, to actual physical conflict. These worries are warranted – protectionism and tariff imposition preceded the massive conflagrations of the First and Second World Wars, although it should also be pointed out that most countries, including the US in the 19th century, industrialised precisely because they protected their domestic enterprises.

However, we also know that the way the world economy is currently configured – a configuration in which unfettered trade between nations is considered sacrosanct – will cause drought, mass poverty, the inundation of coastal areas, a refugee crisis to dwarf anything we have so far experienced and, very likely, physical conflict in just over 20 years.

The fixation on international trade as beneficial and leading to peace, not war, among nations is immensely hard to dislodge. It is, as this article points out, the most venerable of the “numerous ideological shibboleths” of the liberal-capitalist order, which can be traced back to the notion of the 19th century economist David Ricardo that free trade allows countries to exploit their ‘comparative advantage’. Unimpeded trade between nations, said Ricardo, would maximise benefit to consumers and allow for the most efficient use of domestic natural resources.

In time, the notion that countries that trade with each other were unlikely to go to war was added to the carapace justifying unfettered trade. Not only does international trade benefit the consumer but is also forges links of mutual self-interest between nations. Hence, UNCTAD’s synonym for world trade – “economic interdependence”.

In our era, the significance of trade has grown beyond its relevance to the consumer. A lot of trade is now intra-industry. International supply chains allow corporations to shift production or assembling to where it is cheapest (a process known as ‘global labour arbitrage’), while more intricate, technical processes take place in developed countries. The most famous examples are Apple’s iPhone, iPads and iPods. Their components are manufactured in multiple countries – including the US, China, South Korea, Japan, Germany, Switzerland and the Netherlands – but assembled in just one, China. The threads of international trade involved in constructing Apple’s products, and then transporting them to the consumer, are immense.

The transformation that isn’t

But still – in spite of the acknowledged gravity of the situation – proposed solutions to climate change eschew structural change in favour of financial incentives and technological transformation, demonstrating, if nothing else, the stubbornness of the liberal-capitalist faith in international trade.

The IPCC paints a picture of the calamities that will ensue if CO2 emissions are not drastically reduced by 2040 but places its hopes in widespread carbon pricing – charging producers for the amount of CO2 they emit. This is despite the fact that carbon pricing has been introduced by many countries but global emissions have continued to rise.

We need an economic transformation, says the IPCC, for which there is “no documented historical precedent”. But in terms of how to achieve this radical change the well documented precedent of neoliberalism reigns supreme.

The International Maritime Organisation has agreed a non-binding commitment to reduce shipping emissions by 50% by 2050. But the way to achieve this is purely technological. Projections that global trade is to increase dramatically over the coming decades are accepted without question. Rather it is proposed that the currently 50,000-strong global shipping fleet rapidly adopt zero-carbon technology, such as batteries, renewable fuels derived from hydrogen and bioenergy.

Such a transformation is regarded as quite possible with “the correct level of investment”.  Studiously ignored is the fact that investment – the financing of new equipment or machinery – has steadily fallen in advanced capitalist countries, including in export giants like Germany, over the past four decades (see Chart 5.2, p 143). Contemporary, financialised capitalism specialises in extracting profit but not in long-term technological transformation.

Introducing tariffs and stoking trade wars is not the way to achieve the necessary slashing of carbon emissions. Even if it did succeed in reducing emissions – which is far from certain – the consequences are perilous. Notwithstanding the rampant racism involved, rising international tensions might well lead to war.

The rational reduction of global trade

Nonetheless, if climate change is to be mitigated significantly, which must be the aim of any rational political movement, the shibboleth of uninhibited world trade must be tackled. As Naomi Klein says in This Changes Everything, long-haul, energy intensive transport has to be rationed – “reserved for those cases where goods cannot be produced locally or where local production is more carbon-intensive”.

So it falls on the Left to steer a delicate course – reducing world trade in such a way that does not provoke xenophobia and international conflict, economic or physical. This, to be frank, is not an easy task. Jeremy Corbyn’s ‘Build it in Britain’ campaign and assertion that a future Labour government would try to ensure that “we build things here that for too long have been built abroad” was a step in the right direction. But, inevitably, insourcing – the reversal of outsourcing to the other side of the world – is going to have to happen on a large scale.

But there are clear non-capitalist consequences that should be embraced. The ultimate source of profit can be endlessly debated but, in essence, profit is a mark-up over costs. Hence, enormous profits are made from the trading of oil and gas (oil has to be extracted, transported and refined; all occasions for the insertion of profit). However, renewable energy embodies a completely different logic. It does not have to be transported and is freely available. Beyond the high costs of infrastructure development, the price of transmitting the resultant energy to consumers and enterprises, is minimal. There is no reason at all why the production and transmission of renewable energy should be privately owned or a source of profit.

Likewise, the technological future of production, for example 3D Printing, is not for goods to be transported thousands of miles to end markets but to be produced locally. If global trade is to be radically curtailed in the coming years – as it has to be – such a development will likely go with the grain of economic development, not be in conflict with it.

*This process, by the way, wasn’t exclusive to Anglo-European countries. South Korea, a major industrialised country by the 1980s, also shifted production to China and, as a result, trade between the two increased by 1431% between 1995 and 2015.